Arbitrage

Definition and theorem related to arbitrage

finance
mathematics
Author

Eunki Chung

Published

November 4, 2022

What is arbitrage?

We say there’s an arbitrage if we can take some positive return without taking any risk by exploiting some market condition. We can define this notion in mathematical expression as follows.

Definition (Arbitrage)

For a portfolio that has value of \(X_t\) at time \(t \geq 0\), there’s an arbitrage if \(\exists T > 0\) such that the following three conditions hold,

\[ \begin{aligned} 1.\quad &X_0 = 0\\ 2.\quad &X_T \geq 0 \quad \text{a.s.} \\ 3.\quad &P(X_T > 0) > 0\\ \end{aligned} \]

The first condition indicates the portfolio does not require any initial investment. The second condition states that an event of the terminal value is non-negative happens with probability 1, i.e., \(P(X_T \geq 0) = 1\). The third condition implies that the probability of the terminal portfolio value being positive is greater than 0.

Thus, if there is a portfolio that requires zero initial investment but the terminal value will never be less than 0 and there’s a chance to have a positive return, then we say there’s an arbitrage opportunity.

Definition (Equivalence of probability measures)

A probability measure \(\mathbb{\tilde{P}}\) is said to be equivalent to some other probability measure \(\mathbb{P}\), and denoted \(\mathbb{P} \sim \mathbb{\tilde{P}}\) if they agree with the events that occur with probability 1. i.e.,

\[ \mathbb{P}(E) = 1 \iff \Bbb{\tilde{P}}(E) = 1 \]

With the above definition of arbitrage and the notion of equivalent probability measure, we can derive some useful theorem as follows.

Theorem

If \(X\) is arbitrage under some probability measure \(\mathbb{P}\), then it is also arbitrage for any equivalent measure \(\mathbb{\tilde{P}}\).

Proof

Assume that \(\mathbb{P} \sim \mathbb{\tilde{P}}\) and \(X\) is arbitrage under \(\mathbb{P}\) but not arbitrage under \(\mathbb{\tilde{P}}\).

If X is an arbitrage under \(\mathbb{P}\), by the second condition of arbitrage, \[X_T \geq 0 \quad \text{a.s.} \iff \Bbb{P}(X_T \geq 0) = 1\]

Since equivalent probability measure \(\tilde{\mathbb{P}}\) agrees with the event that occurs with probability 1, we have, \[ \mathbb{P}(X_T \geq 0) = 1 \iff \tilde{\mathbb{P}}(X_T \geq 0) = 1 \]

Since we know \(\mathbb{\tilde{P}}(X_T \geq 0) = 1\), X is not an arbitrage if and only if when X violates the third condition under \(\mathbb{\tilde{P}}\). That is, \(\mathbb{\tilde{P}}(X_T > 0) = 0 \iff \mathbb{\tilde{P}}(X_T = 0) = 1\).

However, the equivalent probability measures should agree on all events that occur with probability 1.

Since we have \(\mathbb{P}(X_T > 0) > 0 \iff \mathbb{P}(X_T = 0) \neq 1\), there is a contradiction.

References

Lépinette, Emmanuel. 2019. A short introduction to arbitrage theory and pricing in mathematical finance for discrete-time markets with or without friction. Master. France. https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/cel-02125685.
Lorig, Matt. 2022. “CFRM 504: Lecture Notes.” Department of Applied Mathematics, University of Washington.